Jump to Navigation

Primary Accumulation and the Environment

External Reference/Copyright
Issue date: 
September 27, 2010
Publisher Name: 
SANHATI
Publisher-Link: 
http://sanhati.com
Author: 
Sirisha C. Naidu & Panayiotis T. Manolakos
More like this
SFM
Plantation Management

-----------------

Indian political and economic elites appear to be quite optimistic on various economic, social and environmental questions: there is a satisfactory rate of economic growth, the promulgation of the Forest Rights Act (2006) aims to remedy historical injustices against adivasis, and the country is a leader in the growing market for certified emissions reductions (CERs) that aspires to address global climate change. In addition, capitalist mechanisms have proliferated with the aim of averting environmental disasters whilst providing profitable investment opportunities. “Free market” environmentalism (i.e., green neoliberalism) promotes the ideology of a “win-win” solution such that economic growth is compatible with environmental protection. This view is opposed to certain earlier approaches that framed the environmental question as a trade-off between economic growth and environmental conservation (see Lele 1991).

Yet there have been dilutions of the provisions in environment impact assessments (EIA) in the EIA Notification (see Ministry of Environment and Forests 2009); the undemocratic character of mining-related memoranda of understanding in central and eastern India has become evident; and the struggles in places such as Jagatsinghpur and Niyamgiri raise substantial doubts about human development, ecological sustainability, and democratic decision-making. Certain social groups benefit and others bear the brunt of military, paramilitary, and vigilante offensives for their participation in social movements against conservation and development policies. Free market environmentalism is fraught with the contradictions of capitalist development leading to economic growth at the cost of land dispossession, the loss of access to natural resources, and human relationships with the environment.

In this essay, we consider the relation between capital and nature, and argue that it gravitates toward a policy of primary accumulation [1]. Such a policy has economic and political merits from the perspective of the ruling combine; however, it may not engender human development. These processes of primary accumulation constitute the violent emergence and perpetuation of a regime of capitalist property rights. According to Harvey (2003) the state is a crucial agent of primary accumulation in view of its monopoly over the instruments of violence and the meanings of legality (cf, chapter three in North 1981). The Indian State has amply demonstrated a disposition towards the application of force in the pursuit of a policy of primary accumulation.

The scope for primary accumulation is substantial with respect to the construction of large dams and mining. Notwithstanding the claims of clean energy these are examples of environmentally degrading forms of primary accumulation. Orthodox economic theory approaches such degradation as externalities arising on account of the treatment of nature as an open access resource. According to this school of thought, the solution would be to accord with the diktat of assigning property rights and “getting prices right”. Such a solution to the environmental problem has become politically viable for an assortment of reasons including that the accepted standard of value is posed in the rubrics of market exchange and capitalist property rights. Thus, capital discovers nature as a domain of profitable investment wherein capital supplies environmental commodities to households and firms, aided by changes in markets, environmental valuation techniques, and new technologies (Burkett 2006; Castree 2008; Harvey 2003; Heynen and Robbins 2005). In other words, nature in all its diversity provides ample opportunities for primary accumulation in the cases of large dams (Whitehead 2003), the mining sector, and more recently in terms of free market environmentalism (or green neoliberalism).

Large Dams, Mines, and Free Market Environmentalism

Nature provides a subset of the conditions required for capitalist exploitation of labour power (Burkett 2006). Ecological economists refer to these conditions as the sink and source functions of nature. Capital extracts from nature and expels wastes generated in production and consumption into nature [2]. Such extraction and degradation correlates with primary accumulation and expanded reproduction. The extraction and control of nature is not unique to the capitalist mode of production. Under a capitalist mode of production, on the other hand, a systemic requirement exists for continuous accumulation and expansion, continuous economic growth, and opportunities for profitable investment (see Harvey 2003, 2005).

The Central Statistical Organisation (CSO) recently reported that the rate of growth in aggregate output was approximately 6% over the period 2008.III - 2009.III [3]. In comparison to the Hindu rate of growth, the new exigencies of capital accumulation necessitate increasing the supply of energy and raw materials. This policy has been pursued with great vigour especially with respect to mining and construction of electricity generation capacity. In October 2009, there were 1,53,694 MW of installed capacity; of this total 24% is generated by hydel stations [4]. Presently, there exist 4,072 large dams generating electricity with 453 under construction. Yet the total estimated hydel potential in India is 1,48,702 MW, of which only 31% has been exploited as of March 2008 [5]. In the Himalayan region specifically, 318 hydel projects with a capacity of 93,615 MW are being planned. Of the total estimated potential, 77 percent of hydel capacity remains to be constructed in the Indian Himalayan region and 36 percent in the rest of the country (Dharmadhikary 2008).

The mining sector also exhibited substantial growth. Indeed, the average annual growth of mineral production was 7% during the period 1993-2008 according to the index of mineral production. In contrast, the average annual growth of mineral production was 19.4% over the period beginning in 2006 and ending in March [6]. There were 2,854 mines reported in 2008-09 according to the annual report of the Ministry of Mines for 2008-09 (excluding atomic minerals, crude petroleum, natural gas, and minor metals). An increase in the rate of extraction is evident. Moreover, the value of exports of ores and minerals during 2007-08 was Rs. 95,022 crores (Ministry of Mines 2009). Approximately 14 percent of the value of exports derives from ores and minerals (Bureau of Mines 2009; UNCTAD 2008) [7]. FDI in the mining sector increased from Rs. 196.5 crores to Rs. 2,157 crores from 2006-07 to 2007-08 (Ministry of Mines 2009) [8].

Overextraction and environmental degradation is expected to pose limits to accumulation and expansion, a possibility that O’Connor (1988) refers to as the “second contradiction of capitalism”. However, in various attempts to transcend this contradiction, a new domain for capital accumulation emerges in the rise of a “green” business sector. For the existence and expansion of this sector, capital must acquire de jure or de facto property rights over nature. The resulting environmental commodity may be valued for direct consumption or for its services. Thus, the imperatives of accumulation require uninterrupted and increasing access to environmental goods and services, which is evident not only from the liberalisation of the mining and electricity sectors, but the creation of property rights over an environmental “commodity” as underlies the rationale of the global carbon trade. Despite the rhetoric of sustainable development, such “green” businesses do not necessarily yield ecological and social desiradata.

As an “emerging” economy, it would seem that India does not intend to lag in its extraction from and degradation of nature, nor in its exploitation of nature for profits. Several illustrations of this perspective are contained within a report published by the Global Footprint Network (GFN) and the Confederation of Indian Industry (CII) in 2008. This report opines that the current ecological deficit in India “represents growing market opportunities with significant potential rewards for market leaders” [9]. Furthermore, the report recommends that these market opportunities be exploited by “market leaders” to consolidate their positions in domestic and export markets (GFN and CII 2008). The suggestions of the report are neither fanciful nor wishful. Venture capitalists have invested more than Rs. 2,026 crores in so-called green businesses since 2001, 56% of this sum in 2006; this trend parallels developments in the US, where such investments increased from Rs. 3,837 crores in 2005 to Rs. 11,042 crores in 2006 (Rosen 2007). In 2003, furthermore, the CII persuaded the Andhra Pradesh government to donate land worth Rs. 23 crores in order to open the CII-Godrej Green Business Centre (GBC) in Hyderabad. For this project, USAID provided an investment of Rs. 70 lakh and the CII invested a sum of nine crore rupees [10]. The goal of the GBC is to supply an array of green business promotion services, for example, facilitating private participation in the renewable energy sector, with an expected investment potential of Rs. 6,10,000 crores. Currently, the capitalist sector provides more than 95 percent of total investments in renewable energy in the country. In addition, the report encourages businesses to tap into the Rs. 1,50,000 crores green building material market, and the growing bio-fuels market (GFN and CII 2008).

India’s participation in this free market environmentalism is not restricted to the domestic sphere. The country has a significant presence in the lucrative global market for tradable certified emissions reductions (CERs), which is facilitated by the Clean Development Mechanism (CDM) of the Kyoto Protocol. By March 2009, India gave host country approval to 1,226 projects and 398 of the total 1,455 projects officially registered with the global CDM board are located in India (CDM Authority of India 2009). The Authority estimates that the market value of these projects amounts to Rs. 1,51,397 crores, and expects a payoff of Rs. 26,811 crores from the sale of CERs to clients in industrialized countries by 2012. Indeed, the trading market has been so lucrative that some entities have reported a larger profit from the carbon market than from their main line of business (Kapoor 2006). It is illustrative to note that despite the high ecological and social costs, hydel projects constitute the highest percentage (27%) of CDM projects; in India hydel projects comprise 10% (133 projects) of total CDM projects that have received host approval and 21% of total CERs generated (UNEP/RISOE 2009).

The neoliberal political perspective claims to offer a “win-win” solution for development and sustainability, nevertheless, we doubt the “ecofriendly motivations” of such policy (Castree 2008). Nature is being offered as an outlet for capital accumulation after having been conceived as antagonistic to environmental concerns (Harvey 2005). Perhaps these fixes are undertaken to solve crises, for example, the preservation of sufficient ecological conditions for capitalist production (Burkett 2006) or the problems of overinvestment (Harvey 2005). In any case, the ruling classes attempt to directly control nature via the imposition of capitalist property rights and commodification (e.g., enclosures of the commons), typically utilizing violence and force; they may also indirectly control nature through a neoliberal state (Castree 2008; Harvey 2003).

Ecological Sustainability

There are sufficient examples to suggest that primary accumulation and ecological sustainability are not compatible. Consider the Forest Conservation Acts (1980, and its amendment in1988), which assert that forest conservation is a crucial objective of policy. Despite this, we observe that approximately 12 lakh hectares of forestland were “diverted” during the period 1981-2008. Of these, approximately 11% were acquisitions for “defence” whilst 29.3% were acquisitions for the sum of hydel stations, mining facilities, and irrigation projects, constituting approximately 41% of “diversions” of forestland in total (Ministry of Rural Development 2009) [11]. The neo-Malthusian view that assigns culpability for forest degradation to poor rural households is debatable in comparison to the effects of primary accumulation on ecological sustainability. An additional issue is the recommendation of the Apex Advisory Committee of the Ministry of Mines, which was constituted in order to monitor and review the environmental impacts of mining activities. This Committee recommended that environmental clearances should not be mandatory for mining leases with an area of less than 50 hectares, an increase from the previous limit of 5 hectares, and that a public hearing should not be required for those leases less than 500 hectares (Vagholikar and Moghe 2003). The decision of the Apex Committee does not display much concern for the environment or people’s livelihoods. Perhaps the politico-economic interests governing the behaviour of the Apex Committee and the process of granting forest clearances themselves require scrutiny and rethinking.

Forestland, however, is not only utilized for extractive purposes. The ability of forests to sequester carbon suggests that investments in afforestation and reforestation projects by Annex I countries [12] can be used to offset carbon emissions. Recently, these investments have been termed REDD (reducing emissions from deforestation and environmental degradation) and REDD Plus (combining REDD with payments for environmental services). The World Bank has been quick to jump on to this bandwagon. In India, the World Bank plans to develop 3,500 hectares of tree plantations in Orissa and Andhra Pradesh via the Bank’s bio-carbon fund. These tree plantations are situated on private agricultural land in the possession of medium, small and marginal farmers and would be in the form a buy-back contract for JK Paper Mills Ltd (JKPL) [13]. While JKPL is expected to “help arrange short term credit to farmers for up-front investment costs and provide subsidized planting material, as well as committing to purchase the timber at market prices”, the Bank expects to assist in arranging for long-term credit. Approximately 50% of the land would be planted with eucalyptus trees, which produce good raw material for the paper industry but are environmentally undesirable for their adverse impacts on groundwater, biodiversity, and local vegetation. Unsurprisingly, the project details claim that there will be no negative environmental effects. In addition, the project is expected to sequester at least 0.27 Mt of CO2e by 2017 although there is no mention of the eventual release of carbon into the atmosphere once the trees are harvested to produce pulp for JKPL. India has hitherto been a marginal player in the market for carbon sequestration, having only 13 afforestation and reforestation CDM projects according to UNEP/RISOE (2009), but we expect that this will soon change.

On the other hand, consider the CERs associated with hydel projects. The adverse environmental impacts of large dams are well documented. Yet 21% of India’s certified emissions reductions (or about 14 crores of CERs) are associated with hydel projects (UNEP/RISOE 2009). The total market value of CERs in India is predicted to reach Rs. 26,753 crores by 2012 provided that all CDM projects are registered with the appropriate authorities (CDM Authority of India 2009). Recall that the total estimated hydel potential is 1,48,702 MW, of which only 31% has been exploited as of March 2008. Thus, the CER mechanism provides additional incentives to reinforce the economic basis for the construction of hydel capacity. Similarly, it is expected that projects undertaken under the REDD and REDD Plus mechanisms would encourage ecologically undesirable monoculture plantations. In point of fact, CERs and REDD open a new field of primary accumulation, effectively creating capitalist property rights over the natural commons, often in ecologically sensitive areas. Moreover, such market mechanisms provide incentives for potential speculation at the cost of achieving environmental standards (see Schneider 2007).

The advent of neoliberal environmentalism, in its present constitution, is unlikely to create a “post-material world” in the sense of reducing material throughput (Guha and Martinez-Alier 1997); this is clear from the negotiations at Copenhagen, and the policy initiatives in India and elsewhere. On the contrary, some analysts argue that utilization and degradation of nature is likely to be much more intensive under contemporary conditions of globalization (eg, a high ratio of international to domestic trade, high capital mobility, and dominance of finance over industrial capital) under the World Trade Organization regime (Benton 1999). Global capitalism, with its legal loopholes and power differentials across and within nations, not only makes it impossible to account for social and environmental externalities associated with production and consumption, but also obfuscates the relationship between the product, the producer and the consumer; Princen (1997) calls this the “shading and distancing” of commerce. The diversion of forests, the opening of the mining sector to FDI, and the embrace of the policy of construction of hydel capacity as a mechanism for the accumulation of CERs substantiate our thesis that primary accumulation continues, and has expanded into arenas previously unavailable.

The market solution to the problem of environmental protection consists in the standard of value and appeal to capitalist property rights. This solution to the environmental problem not only subsumes the right to alienate but the right to use nature, its goods, and its services. This method of solution assumes that the price of an environmental commodity fully incorporates its scarcity value and accordingly the rationing mechanism efficiently regulates the use of nature, thus the price mechanism efficiently allocates property rights to uses with the highest return. Notwithstanding the implications for equity, this conviction partly hinges on a failure to appreciate the distinction between absolute and relative scarcity. The notion of absolute scarcity is particularly relevant from an ecological point of view, but especially if one rejects the idea that human-made goods and services are substitutable for all forms of ecological goods and services (see Baumgartner et al 2006). Furthermore, it is unclear whether absolute scarcity is the cause or the result of this “re-institutionalization” as unvalued nature is increasingly brought under a capitalist logic (Heynen and Robbins 2005). Despite efforts by environmental and ecological economists to perfect valuation techniques, market prices may not reflect the total use value of nature.

Concluding Remarks

Habib (1995) observes that the nature of primary accumulation in colonial India transferred wealth originating from non-capitalist sources, proceeding from outside capitalist production, and therefore was a starting point of a new independent circuit of accumulation. Far from being relegated only to the colonial past, however, we continue to observe processes of primary accumulation, which Harvey (2003) refers to as “accumulation by dispossession” (also see Basu and Das 2009; Chatterjee 2008; Sanyal 2007 for relevant discussions). The processes of primary accumulation also exhibit variability over historical time. In many cases these processes include forms of repression, coercion and appropriations, as is evident in conflicts associated with mining and dams. In other cases, different mechanisms extend market control over natural resources via creation of property rights in the flow of returns from, and stock of natural resources. The ideology of free market environmentalism is evident in the imposition of intellectual property rights over biological resources, CERs, and payment for environmental services. These ostensibly protect and enhance human and ecological wellbeing but real dangers remain.

In its myriad forms, primary accumulation corresponds to the dispossession of the means of production and reproduction, and proletarianisation. The processes of primary accumulation discussed in this paper are of concern given the high dependence of the rural poor on natural resources; by some estimates 46.6% of the “GDP of the poor” is derived from natural resources (TEEB 2009). The importance of natural resources to the marginal sections of the Indian society is not wholly captured by this estimate since it fails to consider that these resources provide security in the event of economic and social shocks. This observation is particularly relevant in the current situation with a loss of at least 50 lakh jobs since October 2008 (Prabhu 2009) and drastic increases in food prices. In this context, there is conflict over the regime of property rights whether in the notion of ownership, control or use of nature. While these policies point toward increasing growth, they do not seem to effectively address issues of social, ecological and economic sustainability (see Lele, 1991) as would be expected of a comprehensive and rational policy for sustainability and human development.

References

Bakker, K (2009): “Neoliberal Nature, Ecological Fixes, and the Pitfalls of Comparative Research“, Environment and Planning A, 41(8): 1781-1787.

Basu, D and D Das (2009): “Political Economy of Contemporary India: Some Comments“, Economic and Political Weekly, 44(22): 157-159.

Baumgartner, S., C Becker, M Faber, and R Manstetten (2006): “Relative and Absolute Scarcity of nature. Assessing the roles of economics and ecology for biodiversity conservation“, Ecological Economics, 59(4): 487-498.

Benton, T (1999): “Sustainable Development and Accumulation of Capital: Reconciling the Irreconcilable?” in A Dobson (ed) Fairness and Futurity: Essays of Environmental Sustainability and Social Justice (Oxford: Oxford University Press) 199-232.

Burkett, P (2006): Marxism and Ecological Economics: Toward a Red and Green Political Economy (Boston: Brill).

Castree N (2008): “Neoliberalising nature: Processes, Effects, and Evaluations“, Environment and Planning A, 40(1): 153 – 173.

Chatterjee, P (2008): “Democracy and Economic Transformation in India“, Economic and Political Weekly, 43(16): 19-25.

Dharmadhikary, S (2008): Mountains of Concrete: Dam Building in the Himalayas (Berkeley, California: International Rivers).

Global Footprint Network (GFN) and Confederation of Indian Industry (CII) (2008): India’s Ecological Footprint: A Business Perspective. (Hyderabad: CII).

Guha, R and J Martinez-Alier (1997): Varieties of Environmentalism: Essays North and South (London: Earthscan).

Habib, I (1995): Essays in Indian History (New Delhi: Tulika).

Harvey, D (2003): The New Imperialism (New York: Oxford University Press).

Harvey, D (2005): A Brief History of Neoimperialism (New York: Oxford University Press).

Heynen, N and P Robbins (2005): “The Neoliberalization of Nature: Governance, Privatization, Enclosure and Valuation”, Capitalism, Nature, Socialism, 16(1): 5-8.

Kapoor, A (2006): “Green to Black: India Inc tops Carbon Trading, Firms Cash In“, Indian Express, October 25, 2006.

Lele, S M (1991): “Sustainable Development: A Critical Review.” World Development, 19(6): 607-621.

Ministry of Environment and Forests (2009): “Environment Impact Assessment Notification” S.O. 3067(E), 01/12/2009. (New Delhi: Government of India).

Ministry of Mines (2009): Annual Report 2008-2009 (New Delhi, Government of India).

Ministry of Rural Development (2009): Draft Report of the Committee on State Agrarian Relations and the Unfinished Task of Land Reform Volume I (New Delhi: Government of India).

North, D (1981): Structure and Change in Economic History (New York: Norton).

O’Connor, J (1988): “Nature, socialism: a theoretical introduction“, Capitalism, Nature, Socialism, 1(1): 11-38.

Prabhu, S (2009): “Can conditional cash transfers work in India“, Wall Street Journal, 15 July. Viewed on 10 December 2009 (http://online.wsj.com/article/SB124695317824004689.html)

Princen, T (1997): “The Shading and Distancing of Commerce: When Internalization Is Not Enough“, Ecological Economics, 20(3): 235-253.

Rosen, R (2007): “VCs have put $433 million into ‘green’ businesses since 2001”, Livemint.com, 4 September, Viewed on 20 July 2009. http://www.livemint.com/2007/09/04005349/VCs-have-put-433-million-into.html

Sanyal, K (2007): Rethinking Capitalist Development: Primitive Accumulation, Governmentality and Post-Colonial Capitalism (New Delhi: Routledge).

Schneider, L (2007): “Is the CDM Fulfilling its Environmental and Sustainable Development Objectives: An Evaluation of the CDM and Options for Improvement” (Berlin: World Wildlife Fund).

TEEB (2009): The Economics of Ecosystems and Biodiversity for National and International Policy Makers. (UNEP).

UNEP/Risoe (2009): CDM/JI Pipeline Analysis and Database, 1 December 2009. Viewed on 2 December 2009 (http://cdmpipeline.org/index.htm)

Vagholikar N and K Moghe (2003): Undermining India: Impacts of Mining on Ecologically Sensitive Areas (Pune, Kalpavriksh).

Whitehead, J (2003): “Space, Place and Primitive Accumulation in Narmada Valley and Beyond“, Economic and Political Weekly, 38(40): 4224-4230.

Notes

1. David Harvey (2003) provides a good précis of Marx’s theory of primary accumulation, describing a wide range of processes including expropriation of natural resources.

2. The source and sink functions of nature are often overlapping in view of the multiplicity of the uses of nature.

3. This estimate refers to quarterly GDP at factor cost and constant prices. See the CSO press release at http://mospi.nic.in/estimate_gdp_q3_26feb10.pdf

4. The data were acquired from the website of the Ministry of Power. http://www.powermin.nic.in/JSP_SERVLETS/internal.jsp

5. Data were acquired from the Planning Commission: State-wise Irrigation Potential, Flood Control, Ground Water, Distribution of Large Dams and Hydro Potential Status http://planningcommission.gov.in/data/misdch.html

6. Data acquired from Bureau of Mines http://ibm.gov.in/

7. See the UNCTAD Handbook of Statistics at http://stats.unctad.org/Handbook/TableViewer/tableView.aspx?ReportId=1902

8. All nominal monetary values, which are given as USD in the original source, are converted into Indian rupees at an exchange rate of 46.79 Rs per USD (Hindu Business Line, 21 December 2009).

9. The ecological deficit pertains to the concept of the ecological footprint, which measures the amount of natural resources consumed by a particular country in a given year. A country that consumes in excess of locally available resources is said to have an ecological deficit. India’s per capita ecological footprint was estimated at 0.8 global hectares in 2003, however, available bio-capacity was only 0.4 global hectares per capita. The difference represents either a degradation of available resources or import of resources from around the world (GFN and CII 2008).

10. USAID (2009). Inside India. Newsletter, April 1, 2009,. USAID. http://www.usaid.gov/our_work/economic_growth_and_trade/energy/publications/projects/india_greenbizctr.pdf

11. According to information given by the Minister of State for Environment and Forests in the Lok Sabha on 25 November 2009, a total of 186 projects are pending for environmental clearance and 204 projects are pending for forestry clearance in the ministry as of 20 November 2009. Of those pending for forestry clearance, 46 projects require an area greater than 40 hectares.

12. Annex I countries are industrialized countries in North America, Europe, New Zealand and Australia that are historically responsible for the high level of green house gas (GHG) emissions in the world.

13. Information derived from The World Bank Carbon Finance Unit website http://wbcarbonfinance.org/Router.cfm?Page=About&ItemID=24668

---------------



Extpub | by Dr. Radut